US Life Science: Left to our own Devices?

The other day at UMass Boston, MassMEDIC (the trade organization of Massachusetts medical device companies) held its 16th Annual Conference.  It was well attended, and my prior blog post reported Covidien CEO Jose Almeida’s comments for the advancement of the United States medical device industry.

Another speaker, Yair Holtzman, is a director at WTP Advisers of White Plains, New York, where he focuses on business advisory services to the life science industry.  A CPA and MBA, Yair ambitiously traced the current and future states of R&D in device development.  Let me take a stab at summarizing the high points.

In the past, the United States has been dominant in the medical device market through a combination of its head start with a large number people working within the field, deep expertise, entrepreneurial investment, a robust middle class that drove medical device advances, and a group of patients who could afford to be price-insensitive when it came to buying medical services.  A large number of hospitals, and the leadership of the FDA in device safety, didn’t hurt.

International R&D, as many have noted, is greatly increasing.  Reimbursement has become an issue in the United States, creating concern for ROI that can be derived from R&D efforts.  Added pressure was placed on U.S. ROI for many other reasons, as outlined by Covidien’s Almeida (see the May 1st post).  China and India have growing middle classes and growing expertise; they may well develop medical device products and not even bother to have them cleared in the United States.  Approval of devices in Europe takes half the time of FDA review; Brazil, India and China are becoming very entrepreneurial and are attracting substantial investment.  Germany and Israel have substantial medical device expertise.

For these reasons the United States, historically a leader in the production and consumption of medical device advances, may find itself left behind the rest of the world.

Joining the cacophony in criticizing the Affordable Care Act, which in 2013 will assess a 2.3% excise on the gross income of medical device companies regardless of whether or not a profit has been made, Holtzman anticipated that the effect would be “devastating” and urged that the excise be repealed.  Also in order is a reinstatement of the R&D tax credit, which expired at the end of 2011.

What else must be done in the future?  First, greater speed and predictability must become part of the FDA approval process.  Second, a continuation in the trend to reduce R&D costs through joint ventures and through “farming out” R&D functions must continue.  Third, the industry must recognize certain trends in healthcare: mobile health, personalized medicine, economic efficiency demanded by patients and their reimbursers, and the need for disruptive technologies which will create a paradigm shift in costs and outcomes.  Analytics to demonstrate both health and financial outcomes must become part of device development.

Holtzman observed a trend in the United States to develop incremental products, as opposed to developing disruptive technologies through R&D expenditure, with the “disruptive” perhaps more likely to be generated offshore.  This development is not beneficial to U.S. industry, to say the least.

Holtzman also noted that many VCs are establishing offshore presences, including in Israel and Singapore.  Hopefully some of his recommended changes (at the FDA and in tax policy) will again make domestic United States venture investment in medical device companies attractive, but Holtzman added that his firm has success in identifying grants, state credits and local incentives, as well as joint venturing approaches, in order to drive down R&D costs, speed development and thereby improve ROI.

Interestingly, Holtzman’s remarks also reflected an anomaly which was apparent upon analysis of several recent life science conferences (not just medical devices).  On the one hand, the FDA is praised as setting the standard for review of medical technology which is emulated around the world, and which is one basis for historical American primacy in these markets; on the other hand, the FDA now also is criticized as one of the primary causes of the United States slipping behind the rest of the world.

How Covidien Sees the Med Device World

In conjunction with Mass MEDIC’s 16th Annual Conference, Jose Almeida, who is chairman and president and CEO of Covidien, today put forward a roadmap for what has to be done to retain the United States’ primacy in the medical device field.  Apparently Almeida spends a lot of time thinking about this; he views the role of a CEO as planning what is going to happen ten years down the road (leaving the operation of “today” to others).

His brief shopping list for things that the United States must do:

Expand the coverage of healthcare, but not pay for it by instituting the 2.3% excise tax on gross revenues which will be collected from device companies starting in 2013 under the Affordable Care Act.  Tax burdens reduce R&D expenditures, and it is not logical to tax companies that just happen to operate in the medical field in order to pay for universal healthcare.  One of the effects of this tax burden is to drive companies such as Covidien to undertake hiring not only in the United States but also in China, India and Singapore.

Improve the speed with which the FDA approves products, which now often go to Europe first because of the efficiency of the approval process there.  Slow approval also impacts the economics of VC investments, because it disincentivizes such investments and drives capital offshore.

Address Marketing:  growth overseas of the middle class will drive the need for medical devices, and also require medical device companies to look in detail at their marketing strategies (noting in passing that Covidien is in the process of adding 1,000 sales representatives for its products just in Asia).

Simplify products for sale to lower tier hospitals overseas (interestingly, to achieve this within Covidien, these tasks had to be given to a different team, as the regular R&D team was much more interested in state of the art complexities).

While Almeida reiterated much of what you hear from all large life science companies (and many small companies also) both in the biotech and medical device fields, he makes a powerful case for the necessity of dealing with the Federal government at a granular level in order to maintain United States supremacy in these fields.  With the Affordable Care Act giving rise to (per Almeida) seventeen new federal agencies and their attendant bureaucracies, with the life sciences driving an increase in the number of people at the FDA and the need to increase their pay scale so that turnover at that agency is reduced, and with the negative effects of the upcoming device excise tax, there is a cogent case for substantial realignment of thinking at the Federal level.

And in one area the argument seems absolutely irrefutable: if we are expanding healthcare coverage for the benefit of all, why is the cost to be paid for by an excise only upon an industry that happens to operate within the healthcare system (not to mention that such excise will reduce R&D expenditures and increase the cost of medical devices, two results that are inconsistent with health care policy)?

Red Sox Victorious

The Boston Red Sox scored a major victory last night when their 8pm game against the Yankees was drowned out by torrents of wind-driven rain.  Any game the Sox don’t play these days is counted as a victory.  The team lacks two outfielders, a credible short-stop, predictable starters and any hope at all from the bull-pen.

But failure on the field is not unknown to Red Sox Nation; recent World Series wins set off insane celebration just because everyone knew the Sox were woeful as a general proposition.  Why, now, has the slow start caused such angst among the faithful?  The folks with whom I share season seats have been emailing about this, and there is no shortage of theories.

First, when you expect a lot and don’t get it, you are angry.  For the first time, Sox fans have expectations.

Second, we pay the highest or second highest tariff in the Big Leagues.  At this price point, one can go to a Patriots game and see true brain trauma, so why waste the bucks on so tame a sport as baseball.

Third, there is the carpetbagger syndrome.  We are owned by non-Boston people, and they are not very sympathetic folks at that.  (Principal owner John Henry ties his yacht up at the Boston Harbor Hotel in the summer, and there is something about the winding staircase sweeping up the front of the salon that is, shall we say, lacking in New England frugality.)  Henry’s Boston-based mouthpiece sounds smarmy so the overall feeling is one of, well, invasion.

Just the other day, management invited all true fans to come to the ballpark (America’s most beloved ballpark, they call it; must be true, as it sells out even though half the seats are obstructed view and you take your private parts in your hands if you try to sit on a toilet after the first beer dumping – whoops, I mean the second inning).  Come on over free and have the run of the park.  Morning to night.  People flocked.  Of course, there was no ball game that day.  The idea of a free ballgame would cause management cardiac arrest.  You poor folk can walk the by-ways of Fenway to see how it might feel if you could afford a ticket; noblesse oblige I think the French call it.

Which brings us, fourth, to soccer.  Any true member of Sox Nation knows that soccer is that effete European low-scoring, high-boring, foreign thing that the rest of the world erroneously chooses to call a spectator sport to the detriment of the beautiful symmetry of baseball.  SO —  HOW MUCH did that non-Boston owner (the guy pronounces his Rs in his words, fagodzakes, what the hell is THAT all about) pay to buy a soccer team?  In Europe?  Do you have any idea how many starting pitchers we could have bought with that kind of money spent here in the US of A?  We couldda had Verlander in the bull-pen, facryinoutloud‼

There is still time for the Sox to turn it around.  This year I hear the Major Leagues have added another wild card team to post-season play (MLB is beginning to look like my kid’s Little League: every team gets a trophy, every player an award, there are no losers in the new Valhalla).  But, and this is the shocker, no one cares.  We are watching the Bruins, the Celts, the NFL draft, Nadal playing tennis, Tiger imploding for the umpteenth time (this is really too much punishment for just wandering off the reservation a few times, why take it out on his putts?)….

I hope this is not the end of Red Sox Nation; that powerful marketing combine that posts the number of days of consecutive sell-outs with the breathless fervor of reporting a real score in a real ballgame.  I hope to see the continuing traffic of visitors to Boston who just want to see Fenway Park and don’t care whether the Sox win that particularly game.  I hope Senator Scott Brown, who once urged a Sox move to Foxboro and now advertises the singular grace of a rehabbed Fenway, continues to get seated in one of the eight seats that has both no poles and a visual orientation onto the playing diamond.

So I have a few tickets for games that I cannot use.  Interested?  No scalping, I can give them to you for face value because, well, you’re a true member of the Nation.   … What, no takers?  Hey, these are SOX tickets, ya hear?  SOX SOX SOX, get em while you can, this won’t last forever.

Wait til May, you’ll see.  Then there is always next year….

Public Company Comp in 2012

At the April Breakfast Meeting of the New England Chapter of the National Association of Corporate Directors, a panel of public company directors faced “the Enemy” in the person of Pat McGurn, who represents the ISS.  For the uninitiated, ISS stands for Institutional Shareholder Services, the company that advises institutional shareholders in public companies as to how they might want to vote on director elections and other proxy issues.

McGurn noted that in 2011 the ISS made a favorable recommendation on “say-on-pay” votes in 88% of public companies (that is, ISS recommended that in 7 out of every 8 public companies the shareholders vote in favor of the compensation arrangements proposed by management and the board of directors in the advisory, non-binding shareholder votes mandated by Dodd-Frank).  Although it is early in the current proxy season for 2012, he noted that so far ISS has recommended favorably in 86% of the companies that have come before them.

It should also be noted that historically most companies pass the say-on-pay test with an average positive approval of over 90% of the shareholder votes; in 2011 only 41 companies, or less than 2% of the Russell 3000 Index, actually failed.  Early indications indicate that similar results will obtain in 2012.

McGurn noted that in 2013 the Dodd-Frank Act say-on-pay provisions become applicable to low cap companies for the first time, which may result in different statistics.  That is, if there is no change in the Federal administration, the suggestion being that a Republican victory might lead to a delay in implementation.  He noted that the April 5th JOBS Act signed by the President delayed many otherwise mandated compensation disclosures for newly registered companies with sales below $1,000,000,000 which is, after all, most of them.

What was the effect of a negative ISS recommendation in 2011?  According to McGurn, all but a small handful of boards receiving negative ISS recommendations, whether or not they received negative shareholder votes, responded in some fashion.  Almost all companies changed their compensation to link it better to actual performance.  Each of the three companies who received negative votes in 2011 and who have already had their 2012 annual meetings have received over 90% approval in their 2012 say-on-pay votes by the shareholders.

The key is not only changing compensation to link it to company performance; the key is also outreach to investors to understand and meet their reactions.  Disclosure is much better of course, and this facilitates communication, but some companies also have been doing formal compensation roadshows.

The problems with compensation are no longer extra perks, severance and the like, which McGurn described merely as “irritants.”  The issues now are actually tying compensation to performance, and addressing executive compensation which is a multiple of peer group mean compensation.

There is something of a contrast between this relatively self-satisfied ISS report, on the one hand, and the extensive article in this past Sunday’s New York Times Business Section concerning executive pay.  Discussing pay for the top fifty public company executives whose information has already been reported in this proxy season, the Times article concludes that while executive compensation growth may have leveled off, it has leveled off at an extremely high point in terms of absolute dollars.  Even taking Apple’s CEO out of the equation (earning something in excess of $378,000,000, although most of it was indeed in stock and not cash), CEO compensation in numerous business sectors was significant.

The panelists, chairs of compensation committees of public companies, had differing reactions.  One panelist noted that, in a highly successful company where compensation was discretionary (but it turns out not above mean), there was resistance to having ISS force mathematical metrics into the equation in order to define and calculate appropriate compensation.  There was also criticism of an over-emphasis on “total shareholder return” which is an important ISS metric; in technology companies with high potential volatility, an executive can be doing an excellent job and yet profitability can take a short term beating because of the realities of the marketplace.

The ISS response was that they have lengthened their time horizon by which they are comfortable in measuring corporate performance, to take pressure off the very short term, but McGurn did note that his clients (ISS’s clients) are long-term investors, and at some point total shareholder return on investment becomes “the” metric in which his clients have an interest.

There was also discussion of the somewhat opaque selection of peer groups in which ISS places each company (so that compensation can be measured against what are putatively the company’s peers).  McGurn noted that each company is placed in a peer group wherein that company is placed near the mean in terms of size, further noting that one of the largest determinants of absolute compensation is indeed the size of enterprise.

In 2012, ISS sees as its hot spot the payment of executive compensation above the peer mean by companies showing mediocre performance, although McGurn assured the group that ISS has no particular performance metric and that each company is entitled to have its own metrics; what he is looking for, he says, is “evidence of intelligent design” as opposed to a rote set of numbers.

Finally, the panel noted that an effort was being made to address the ratio of CEO compensation to the compensation paid to the rest of the executive team; they declared an end to “the rock star CEO.”  That announcement may come as a surprise to readers of the New York Times CEO survey.

Bentham Meets Obama (or, when Courts should shut up)

Jeffrey Toobin’s lead article in the April 9 New Yorker is a clear and convincing argument for the liberal viewpoint on the Supreme Court’s role in evaluating Romneycare – whoops, I mean Obamacare.  As befits a graduate of THE Law School, Toobin applies the power of court precedent to the debate, finds that the law should be sustained, and excoriates Court conservatives for replacing judicial process with personal bias and a lack or respect for the elected representatives of the people.

We should pause to note that Toobin, for about twenty years the legal guru at New Yorker and more recently at CNN, writes with convincing clarity and hits from the left side of the plate.  Neither of these facts make him wrong —  but neither guarantees that he is correct, either.

Toobin notes extrinsic pressures on the Court deliberations: politics.  It is hard to know the degree to which the Justices will internalize political realities in their judgments.  His analogy to the Roosevelt Supreme Court reversing in 1937 its conservative bias (most importantly expressed by the Court striking down the NRA in the 1935 “sick chicken case”), thereby reflecting an appropriate appreciation for the presumed validity of Congressional Acts passed by elected officials, seems misguided; likely, fear of Roosevelt packing the Court was a greater driver of the Supreme Court changing direction.

What is not discussed by Toobin is the role of social values underlying the debate.  The article’s suggestion that the conservatives on the Court are applying not only unprecedented standards but also their own sense of our Social Compact to the detriment of “THE LAW,” is implicit and not stated but, I suspect, can be found one layer deeper in the Toobin onion.

For example, his moral outrage over this same Court declaring corporations to be people in Citizens United is echoed in Toobin’s clear moral contempt for questions directed from conservative Justices to the Solicitor General that suggest sympathy for the insurance companies which are subject to Romney/Obamacare.

Every branch of our government reflects the sense of the electorate (that part which votes) as to the current nature of our Social Compact.  We, or some of us, elect two branches and one branch names the third; to say that Justices are not elected is true only in the technical sense.  And to suggest as does Toobin that conservative social thinking is polluting the judgment of conservative Justices is just another way of saying that people are messing with the liberal social thinking that for several decades of the 20th Century in fact dominated the content of our legal precedent.  It is not that improper social thoughts are taking over our Courts; rather, it is that social thoughts that liberals do not share are taking over our Courts.

Enter another way to think about the debate; it is a way that is not Constitutionally premised, but rather is reflective of what underlies our governance and what is (imperfectly) reflected in our voting.  What would Jeremy Bentham and John Stewart Mill, the utilitarian philosophers, do if they were on the Court?

Likely they would be blind to the Constitutional arguments although that would be a shame; the primacy of the rule of precedential law is pretty important and not often shared outside the legal profession.  I am sure they would ignore the pressure of the election.  But they would, as all people must, bring their understanding of our society’s “Deal” with itself to the deliberations.  And their understanding is neither conservative nor liberal, it is utilitarian.

Now there are various schools of utilitarianism and I am going to do disservice to all of them (and reveal no doubt a lack of deep knowledge) by reducing the whole lot to a simple proposition: best governmental decisions provide the greatest good and happiness to the greatest number.  Put another way – my way  —  we should look to weight benefit and burden.  That mathematics multiples the number of benefited by the amount of benefit, and balances it against the number of burdened multiplied by the amount of burden.  The best answer is told by the way in which the balance tips.

So who is benefited by Romney/Obamacare?  Arguably most people.  Those without current coverage?  Yes.  Those with existing coverage?  Likely so; I know that when I pay my horrendous premiums I am already paying for many who are not covered; it is implicit in the costs of the care I receive that I am covering the uninsured who by and large are being treated anyway at hospitals and by doctors that I, and others like me, do already pay for. The insurance companies?  As regulated entities, which particularly under Romney/Obamacare cannot be allowed to fail, they will get funded by premiums and governments.

Who is burdened?  Everyone who pays taxes certainly.  But query if they are paying in the long run more than they are paying now by reason of presently paying for their own care and (in an inefficient way) the care of the “uninsured.”  Individuals whose freedom is infringed by being forced to buy a product they do not want?  I find that a facially logical proposition that plays to our legitimate sense of freedom but is unconvincing.  We already are forced to “buy” an infinity of things that we may not want.  How about certain military adventures?  Farm subsidies? Pork barrel? Pick your pet peeve that your tax dollars go to.  Would Bentham much care about the argument that the government could fund universal health care by tax but cannot do so by Romney/Obamacare, when the functional result and economic costs seem roughly the same?

Our “freedoms” are impinged mightily every single day by government, and that is a wholly separate and legitimate discussion, but is not significantly addressed by saying that Romney/Obamacare should be stricken because government is forcing us to buy a commercial product.

None of the above of course reflects an independent moral judgment, which is the degree to which our society should afford medical care to people not receiving it.  There are two flavors of what is now happening in medical care: many receive it free and we are paying for it anyway and inefficiently to boot; or, some do not receive it at all, which ought to present a moral conundrum to many.   (Indeed, some people from whom I hear the argument against the law apply the moral standard privately in their charity but do not see the government as the mechanism to bring moral judgment to medical care, although our government does and must bring moral judgment to almost anything it does do, and by definition).

We will have our answers by the end of June when the Court concludes its current session and must report out its decisions on all cases it has heard.  The Court spent three days hearing arguments that I submit will not drive the decision.  The decision will be decided by preconceived notions of the Social Compact on the part of eight Justices, and some unknowable tortured process undertaken by Justice Kennedy, who so often is the “swingman” between the entrenched personal philosophies of the others.

We as observers are so politicized in the way we see things that we may miss the real battle here, but that battle also may not be express in what is expected to be multiple written decisions of the Court, as it is not express in Toobin’s New Yorker article.

And the Justices will decide,  based on whatever has happened to each of them beforehand, and which brought them to the legal, intellectual and emotional place which each now occupies.  Perhaps, as in Bob Dylan’s words, “A man hears what he wants to hear and disregards the rest.”

Jeffrey Toobin’s lead article in the April 9 New Yorker is a clear and convincing argument for the liberal viewpoint on the Supreme Court’s role in evaluating Romneycare – whoops, I mean Obamacare.  As befits a graduate of THE Law School, Toobin applies the power of court precedent to the debate, finds that the law should be sustained, and excoriates Court conservatives for replacing judicial process with personal bias and a lack or respect for the elected representatives of the people.

We should pause to note that Toobin, for about twenty years the legal guru at New Yorker and more recently at CNN, writes with convincing clarity and hits from the left side of the plate.  Neither of these facts make him wrong —  but neither guarantees that he is correct, either.

Toobin notes extrinsic pressures on the Court deliberations: politics.  It is hard to know the degree to which the Justices will internalize political realities in their judgments.  His analogy to the Roosevelt Supreme Court reversing in 1937 its conservative bias (most importantly expressed by the Court striking down the NRA in the 1935 “sick chicken case”), thereby reflecting an appropriate appreciation for the presumed validity of Congressional Acts passed by elected officials, seems misguided; likely, fear of Roosevelt packing the Court was a greater driver of the Supreme Court changing direction.

What is not discussed by Toobin is the role of social values underlying the debate.  The article’s suggestion that the conservatives on the Court are applying not only unprecedented standards but also their own sense of our Social Compact to the detriment of “THE LAW,” is implicit and not stated but, I suspect, can be found one layer deeper in the Toobin onion.

For example, his moral outrage over this same Court declaring corporations to be people in Citizens United is echoed in Toobin’s clear moral contempt for questions directed from conservative Justices to the Solicitor General that suggest sympathy for the insurance companies which are subject to Romney/Obamacare.

Every branch of our government reflects the sense of the electorate (that part which votes) as to the current nature of our Social Compact.  We, or some of us, elect two branches and one branch names the third; to say that Justices are not elected is true only in the technical sense.  And to suggest as does Toobin that conservative social thinking is polluting the judgment of conservative Justices is just another way of saying that people are messing with the liberal social thinking that for several decades of the 20th Century in fact dominated the content of our legal precedent.  It is not that improper social thoughts are taking over our Courts; rather, it is that social thoughts that liberals do not share are taking over our Courts.

Enter another way to think about the debate; it is a way that is not Constitutionally premised, but rather is reflective of what underlies our governance and what is (imperfectly) reflected in our voting.  What would Jeremy Bentham and John Stewart Mill, the utilitarian philosophers, do if they were on the Court?

Likely they would be blind to the Constitutional arguments although that would be a shame; the primacy of the rule of precedential law is pretty important and not often shared outside the legal profession.  I am sure they would ignore the pressure of the election.  But they would, as all people must, bring their understanding of our society’s “Deal” with itself to the deliberations.  And their understanding is neither conservative nor liberal, it is utilitarian.

Now there are various schools of utilitarianism and I am going to do disservice to all of them (and reveal no doubt a lack of deep knowledge) by reducing the whole lot to a simple proposition: best governmental decisions provide the greatest good and happiness to the greatest number.  Put another way – my way  —  we should look to weight benefit and burden.  That mathematics multiples the number of benefited by the amount of benefit, and balances it against the number of burdened multiplied by the amount of burden.  The best answer is told by the way in which the balance tips.

So who is benefited by Romney/Obamacare?  Arguably most people.  Those without current coverage?  Yes.  Those with existing coverage?  Likely so; I know that when I pay my horrendous premiums I am already paying for many who are not covered; it is implicit in the costs of the care I receive that I am covering the uninsured who by and large are being treated anyway at hospitals and by doctors that I, and others like me, do already pay for. The insurance companies?  As regulated entities, which particularly under Romney/Obamacare cannot be allowed to fail, they will get funded by premiums and governments.

Who is burdened?  Everyone who pays taxes certainly.  But query if they are paying in the long run more than they are paying now by reason of presently paying for their own care and (in an inefficient way) the care of the “uninsured.”  Individuals whose freedom is infringed by being forced to buy a product they do not want?  I find that a facially logical proposition that plays to our legitimate sense of freedom but is unconvincing.  We already are forced to “buy” an infinity of things that we may not want.  How about certain military adventures?  Farm subsidies? Pork barrel? Pick your pet peeve that your tax dollars go to.  Would Bentham much care about the argument that the government could fund universal health care by tax but cannot do so by Romney/Obamacare, when the functional result and economic costs seem roughly the same?

Our “freedoms” are impinged mightily every single day by government, and that is a wholly separate and legitimate discussion, but is not significantly addressed by saying that Romney/Obamacare should be stricken because government is forcing us to buy a commercial product.

None of the above of course reflects an independent moral judgment, which is the degree to which our society should afford medical care to people not receiving it.  There are two flavors of what is now happening in medical care: many receive it free and we are paying for it anyway and inefficiently to boot; or, some do not receive it at all, which ought to present a moral conundrum to many.   (Indeed, some people from whom I hear the argument against the law apply the moral standard privately in their charity but do not see the government as the mechanism to bring moral judgment to medical care, although our government does and must bring moral judgment to almost anything it does do, and by definition).

We will have our answers by the end of June when the Court concludes its current session and must report out its decisions on all cases it has heard.  The Court spent three days hearing arguments that I submit will not drive the decision.  The decision will be decided by preconceived notions of the Social Compact on the part of eight Justices, and some unknowable tortured process undertaken by Justice Kennedy, who so often is the “swingman” between the entrenched personal philosophies of the others.

We as observers are so politicized in the way we see things that we may miss the real battle here, but that battle also may not be express in what is expected to be multiple written decisions of the Court, as it is not express in Toobin’s New Yorker article.

And the Justices will decide,  based on whatever has happened to each of them beforehand, and which brought them to the legal, intellectual and emotional place which each now occupies.  Perhaps, as in Bob Dylan’s words, “A man hears what he wants to hear and disregards the rest.”

Impediments to Bio Industry Expansion

The Massachusetts Biotechnology Council meeting on The Business of Science concluded March 27, as it began: lots of discussion of the technology, interspersed with programs about the business and financial aspects of bio which all had the same themes: bio is the great wave of the future, Massachusetts is at the forefront, but other geographic bio clusters are hot on our heels and there are many ways we in Massachusetts can be overtaken and surpassed.

One interesting counterpoint came from an Indian panelist who noted that the suppositions that FDA was too slow and too conservative to the detriment of US bio in general, are simply inaccurate.  Notwithstanding the oft-recited tales of horrible delay in FDA, the timing of drug approval overseas in not faster and will not become faster because other countries rely on FDA to set the tone and the standard of review.  This assertion was not directly challenged but was, alas, simply ignored; the final speaker, who was from FDA, was asked in several ways why the FDA moved so slowly.

The FDA position, by the way, articulated by  Dr. Eric Perakslis (Informatics chief), is that they DO hurry when there is a clear unmet medical need; the FDA will be willing to incur risk if the benefit seems to balance it.  The biggest problem the FDA has these days, he noted, was in their newly established regulatory function over tobacco, where he wondered how to measure benefits against risks for a product having no benefits at all.  (My best guess is that Eric is not a big smoker.)

What is impeding Mass bio?  The state gifts ban (which kills interaction that leads to innovation); the unique Massachusetts ban on co-payment assistance which thereby imperils the payment stream; the failure of schools from elementary to Community colleges to train workers in requisite skill sets; anti-immigration laws that now overly restrict special visas; a lack of language skills among our workforce members; lack of government  funded apprenticeships in private industry thereby impeding hiring of skilled and experienced workers; the growth of viable bio clusters elsewhere with governmental support superior to that afforded in Massachusetts (citing particularly Germany and Singapore).

The attendees are all “bio people” and it is hard to separate their valid but survivable complaints from the truly existential threats to Massachusetts biotech companies; every industry has its burdens to bear, and bio is not the only industry that fairly can say that it is over-regulated, under-served by government, not supported by the educational system and, these days, denied essential capital.

The one extremely positive message that came out of the meeting, however, and one message shared by attendees from within and outside  Massachusetts, is that everyone today believes that Massachusetts has innate advantages in Higher Education and entrepreneurship and that therefore, given appropriate nurturing, bio will be an economic and social engine for the region for a very long time.

Risk, Regulation, and the American Economy: Dialogue with a Professional Director

Ernie Godshalk is a professional director currently sitting on two public boards; a director of the National Association of Corporate Directors/New England, Ernie is well known to the local director community as a thoughtful commentator on board service.

His current view of the world economy is that it is recovering slowly but subject to substantial risks, and heading the list are the precarious nature of the Euro (I parenthetically note today’s report of further weakening in the Euro countries’ employment) and the international risks created by Iran and perhaps Pakistan.  In light of this view, I asked how a board should go about enterprise risk management.

Godshalk’s view is that, while his boards discuss risk virtually every meeting and care is given to identifying who is responsible for watching which risks, there are indeed some existential exposures which cannot be controlled by the company and consequently cannot really be monitored.

Ernie expressed concern as to the impact of any Euro failure on the highly leveraged Deutsche Bank, and rejected the view that a Euro failure in the long run would not represent a substantial risk for United States businesses.  Certainly, identifying non-European markets for the purchase of parts or the sale of goods, and the shortening of lead times, can mediate the Euro risk to some extent, but substantial risk will remain given the international nature of United States business.

What are the problems most plaguing our economy, aside from major geopolitical risks?  We discussed excessive US regulation; we further debated whether over-regulation was an annoyance and a marginal expense but not an ultimate depressor of United States business.  Godshalk noted two factors in the American environment that he thought were significant: first, our high tax rate and, second, our immigration policy.

Noting the internationalization of business in general, even domestic United States companies have substantial opportunity to relocate operations and profits overseas.  Higher United States tax rates drive that flight abroad.

Immigration is an oft-cited problem, as it has become difficult to obtain visa approval for persons with requisite skills to drive technology businesses.  Even more anomalously, I suggested that we are now bringing foreign students to the United States and transferring our own sophisticated technology to them and, then, refusing to allow them to stay; it is the forced exportation of our technological advantage.

Asked about the biggest problems in serving as a director these days, Godshalk noted two: first, failure of boards properly to address CEO succession; and, second, the inordinate time which boards must apply to risk assessment, say-on-pay, proxy solicitation and the like, which diverts the board from its strategic mission of “adding value” and making the company business better.

Finally, I asked Ernie about the current state of the M&A market.  From a strategic acquisition standpoint, he believes that good deals are available.  The strategic advantage should be in either technology or in sales (for example, efficiency in marketing multiple lines).  In response to the suggestion that an improving M&A market has caused an increase in EBITDA multiples, particularly for strategic acquirors, Ernie noted that there are many companies that are for sale, there is pent up sales demand, and many enterprises with VC and PE money remain well “behind plan” by reason of the recent business recession, and consequently are favorably priced.

The issue of over-regulation of United States business is and will remain a significant discussion.  Two days before our meeting, the Congress passed and sent to the President the JOBS Act, which rolls back some of the Dodd-Frank regulatory requirements at least for businesses that are now going public with sales less than $1,000,000,000 (which is not all of them, but surely most of them).  Now that the Federal Administration identifies relationship between regulation and employment, it is possible that bi-partisan efforts (so hard to achieve in so many areas) will nonetheless continue to address these issues of over-regulation which Godshalk believes drive companies abroad and waste director time in boardrooms.

Funding Bio– MassBio Conference doesn’t know how to do it

The Massachusetts Biotechnology Council’s program entitled “2012 Annual Meeting – the Business of Science” is underway, and the kick-off keynote speech and first panel spent a good deal of time exploring why the business approach to funding bio is not working so well.

Francis Collins is the Director of the National Institutes of Health and thus a major player in the business of bio; this year he will give out $25.7  billion to about 325,000 scientists.  His speech was sprinkled with insights and great factoids, but the bottom line is that bio is in financial trouble and he is driving NIH to help meet the issues.  Only about one in every six applicants gets funded these days, and the NIH budget has declined about 20% in buying power over the last decade even though the absolute number of dollars has increased.

Most telling: a 60-year longitudinal chart showing that over that period the number of successful drugs reaching market for each $1 billion of investment has fallen 100-fold.  Although expressing himself as optimistic, citing great advances in the genomic sphere which  will speed diagnosis and specific targeted treatment of cancer and other diseases, he conceded that bio contributes wealth (as well as wellness) to our nation, and that competition in China, India, Russia and now Europe is heating up.  He intends on Wednesday to make these points to the Senate in discussing NIH funding.

(I found myself seated at a table with a representative of the UK government, who listed the UK funds established in the last few months, with many hundreds of millions of pounds to invest in bio, including a 200,000,000 government fund;  you could almost feel the breath of John Bull down the necks of the attendees.)

How to fight for U.S. supremacy in bio?  Efficient use of genomic analysis to speed drug targeting and testing, a study of failed or seldom used drugs to see if they have different applications, effective use of iPS cells which can be differentiated and then studied specifically.  And, continued NIH funding, and an additional federal fund to supplement NIH and to target major needs such as Alzheimer’s.

The panel that followed was a bit more harsh in its analysis; moderated by Juan Enriquez, Managing Director of Excel Venture Management, the panel blamed the by-now usual suspects: the FDA, the non-economic models for drug development which turn off VC investment, the greater ease to acquire drugs as compared to spending 15 years developing and testing them.  Some compared drug companies today to Procter and Gamble: more interested in marketing than in science.

One panelist noted that it is worse than feared: not only do few drugs get approved, but only 3 in 10 which are approved ever earn enough money to provide a return on investment.  Drugs being proposed these days need have not only a scientific story but also a consideration as to pricing and reimbursement issues before investors will consider them.

Growth by acquisition cannot continue, as “pharma is running out of merger partners.”  The benefits of scale will no longer be available.  Schools bear blame also, by restricting doctors from serving on company boards or taking stock.

One final question hung over the room at the end: if drugs can come to market overseas for less money and in four years, what is the future of bio in the U.S.  (There being no ready response, the program moved on to simpler things, like the cure for cancer….)

DEMOCRACY IN ACTION?

This morning’s mail has upset a part of my world view.

Universities long have been accused of being bastions of populist, liberal thought; Northeastern elite universities (along with anomalous Berkeley, the Harvard of the West) have borne the brunt of this accusation.

Such was not my experience at Harvard Law School; during my attendance (decades ago) it was the bastion of pro-corporate thinking.  Corporations should be minimally regulated so as to return greatest profit to their sole relevant constituency: the shareholders.

My 7:44 AM email today from The Harvard Law School Shareholder Rights Project reports that that group, “a clinical program through which Harvard Law School faculty, staff and students assist public pension funds and charitable organizations to improve corporate governance at publicly traded companies in which they are shareowners,” has been working all year to force public companies to de-stagger their boards.

They have submitted proposals to over 80 of the S&P 500, and 42 (one third of the S&P 500 with staggered boards) have agreed to move to annual elections of the entire board.  The list includes Alcoa, BlackRock, Cigna, Lilly, McDonald’s and PPG.

Several aspects are fascinating.  Leave it to Harvard to apply some of its student outrage in the support of retirement funds who have invested in public companies; not exactly the poor huddled masses being dragged upwards by the power of the law.  Leave it to Harvard to take the training ground of the conservative corporate advisors and turn it towards the “democratization” of corporate governance.  Leave it to Harvard to undertake the remaking of concepts of corporate governance in a way that empowers shareholders whose interests may be short-term and inconsistent with long-term measured corporate growth.

It is not clear where they will turn next, but this kind of success is not going to do anything except further inspire Professor Bebchuck and his hearty band.  The shopping list of corporate democracy demands includes broad proxy access, greater ratchet on comp,  independent board chairs, and independent board majorities.

While no doubt entrenched boards beholden to management sometimes in the past led to failure to respond to favorable takeover bids and to over-compensation of top executives, the causes for these lapses are many and complex and cannot be made to disappear by granting greater power to shareholders.  The small shareholder is and will remain without power.  The larger shareholders have, and are legally entitled to, their own agendas; those agendas may be short term and short sighted and not consistent with healthy corporate growth or innovation.

Two lessons emerge: first, this initiative will ultimate fuel the M&A market; second, directors had better start listening more closely to Professor Bebchuck, whose message and flat presentation have not exactly made him the darling of the corporate speakers’ circuit around Boston.  He is single-handedly remaking corporate governance in America and he is doing it under many radar screens that ought to be picking up the incoming blips.

Directors and Company Founders

The March 13 breakfast meeting at National Association of Corporate Directors (New England) brought together two extremely successful business founders, together with veteran company director Ernie Godshalk, to examine the relationship between boards of directors and founders.

The two founders on the panel are atypical: each has  grown multi-billion dollar companies and has survived as both chair of the board and CEO of the enterprise.  That doesn’t mean they didn’t add executive strength below; it just means they were able successfully to stay in the saddle and have dynamic success.

Allen McKim is Chair, President and CEO of Clean Harbors, with 500 locations in the United States, Canada, Mexico and Puerto Rico and with international operations in many other places.  Josef von Rickenbach is Chairman and CEO of Parexel, a bio pharmaceutical services company.  Both companies were founded in the ‘80s and are publicly held.  Clean Harbors was founded with a loan against McKim’s house; von Rickenbach started in his basement and now has 12,000 employees.

In terms of corporate governance, their paths were diverse.  McKim with Clean Harbors had a close-knit board until the IPO; now there are nine independents and McKim.  Von Rickenbach had early VC investment, and said that this created a level of process and formality which stayed with the company.

What they both have in common is an ability to use the board as a tool.  Each noted that independent directors create a sounding board, and a learning experience, for the successful entrepreneur.

What circumstances lead to blow-outs between boards and founders?  Godshalk noted that the relationship between a founder and an independent board can be tense; the founder may even be asked to exclude himself from certain board discussions, while the founder is used to being on the top of the hierarchy.  Also, when a private equity firm becomes involved and gets board seats, the situation can become volatile because of the perhaps shorter patience of the investors.

McKim noted that his company hit a wall at around $90,000,000 in sales, and the board then guided him in finding outside management to grow the enterprise.  Von Rickenbach noted that he always treated the board as “his boss” but observed that it is necessary to be a good boss, to show up and to be prepared and to understand that a board is not hands-on with respect to execution.

While each entrepreneur remains as chairman, each board has a lead director in which substantial responsibility resides.  Each CEO indicated that he had staffed the board to track the direction of the business.  When Waste Management moved focus from the utilities industry to oil and gas, McKim added directors with knowledge in that field, and Parexel (which does a lot of work overseas) moved for geographic diversity.

A discussion of board-building, which actually has application to all boards whether or not the company is founder-run, developed several other themes:

*When asked about diversity generally, the panel noted that diversity of views of business and of science, not just gender or ethnic diversity, was desirable.

*Godshalk noted that building boards around business expertise as a company evolved tracked the desirable approach of building a board through creating a “skills matrix” and then looking for people who can fill those particular slots.

*The panel seemed to like the idea of sending a founder to serve on other boards, perhaps at larger companies, as part of the founder’s educational process.

*Suspicion of age limits and mandatory retirement was expressed; boards should retain people of merit whose board evaluations are strong, regardless of age.

*In conversation after the meeting, it was also noted (Bob Popeo from Mintz Levin) that age limits were on their way out; as companies have soured on the idea of their CEOs sitting on other boards, that role has fallen more and more to CEOs who have retired and therefore are older.